Cost-Push Inflation vs. Demand-Pull Inflation: What's the Difference?

Cost-Push Inflation vs. Demand-Pull Inflation: An Overview

There are four main drivers behind inflation. Among them are cost-push inflation, or the decrease in the aggregate supply of goods and services stemming from an increase in the cost of production, and demand-pull inflation, or the increase in aggregate demand, categorized by the four sections of the macroeconomy: households, business, governments, and foreign buyers. The two other contributing factors to inflation include an increase in the money supply of an economy and a decrease in the demand for money.

Inflation is the rate at which the general price level of goods and services rises. This, in turn, causes a drop in purchasing power. This is not to be confused with the change in the prices of individual goods and services, which rise and fall all the time. Inflation happens when prices rise across the economy to a certain degree.

Key Takeaways

  • Cost-push inflation is the decrease in the aggregate supply of goods and services stemming from an increase in the cost of production.
  • Demand-pull inflation is the increase in aggregate demand, categorized by the four sections of the macroeconomy: households, business, governments, and foreign buyers.
  • An increase in the costs of raw materials or labor can contribute to cost-pull inflation.
  • Demand-pull inflation can be caused by an expanding economy, increased government spending, or overseas growth.

Cost-Push Inflation

Aggregate supply is the total volume of goods and services produced by an economy at a given price level. When the aggregate supply of goods and services decreases because of an increase in production costs, it results in cost-push inflation.

Cost-push inflation means prices have been "pushed up" by increases in the costs of any of the four factors of production—labor, capital, land, or entrepreneurship—when companies are already running at full production capacity. Companies cannot maintain profit margins by producing the same amounts of goods and services when their costs are higher and their productivity is maximized.

The price of raw materials may also cause an increase in costs. This may occur because of a scarcity of raw materials, an increase in the cost of labor to produce the raw materials, or an increase in the cost of importing raw materials. The government may also increase taxes to cover higher fuel and energy costs, forcing companies to allocate more resources to paying taxes.

In order to compensate, the increase in costs is passed on to consumers, causing a rise in the general price level: inflation.

For cost-push inflation to occur, demand for goods must be static or inelastic. That means demand must remain constant while the supply of goods and services decreases. One example of cost-push inflation is the oil crisis of the 1970s. The price of oil was increased by OPEC countries, while demand for the commodity remained the same. As the price continued to rise, the costs of finished goods also increased, resulting in inflation.

Let's take a look at how cost-push inflation works using this simple price-quantity graph. The graph below shows the level of output that can be achieved at each price level. As production costs increase, aggregate supply decreases from AS1 to AS2 (given production is at full capacity), causing an increase in the price level from P1 to P2. The rationale behind this increase is, for companies to maintain or increase profit margins, they will need to raise the retail price paid by consumers, thereby causing inflation.

Cost push
Image by Julie Bang © Investopedia 2019

Demand-Pull Inflation

Demand-pull inflation occurs when there is an increase in aggregate demand, categorized by the four sections of the macroeconomy: households, businesses, governments, and foreign buyers.

When concurrent demand for output exceeds what the economy can produce, the four sectors compete to purchase a limited amount of goods and services. That means the buyers "bid prices up" again and cause inflation. This excessive demand, also referred to as "too much money chasing too few goods," usually occurs in an expanding economy.

In Keynesian economics, an increase in aggregate demand is caused by a rise in employment, as companies need to hire more people to increase their output.

The increase in aggregate demand that causes demand-pull inflation can be the result of various economic dynamics. For example, an increase in government spending can increase aggregate demand, thus raising prices. Another factor can be the depreciation of local exchange rates, which raises the price of imports and, for foreigners, reduces the price of exports. As a result, the purchasing of imports decreases while the buying of exports by foreigners increases. This raises the overall level of aggregate demand, assuming aggregate supply cannot keep up with aggregate demand as a result of full employment in the economy.

Rapid overseas growth can also ignite an increase in demand as more exports are consumed by foreigners. Finally, if a government reduces taxes, households are left with more disposable income in their pockets. This, in turn, leads to an increase in consumer confidence that spurs consumer spending.

Looking again at the price-quantity graph, we can see the relationship between aggregate supply and demand. If aggregate demand increases from AD1 to AD2, in the short run, this will not change aggregate supply. Instead, it will cause a change in the quantity supplied, represented by a movement along the AS curve. The rationale behind this lack of shift in aggregate supply is that aggregate demand tends to react faster to changes in economic conditions than aggregate supply.

As companies respond to higher demand with an increase in production, the cost to produce each additional output increases, as represented by the change from P1 to P2. That's because companies would need to pay workers more money (e.g., overtime) and/or invest in additional equipment to keep up with demand. Just like cost-push inflation, demand-pull inflation can occur as companies pass on the higher cost of production to consumers to maintain their profit levels.

Demand pull
Image by Julie Bang © Investopedia 2019

Special Considerations

There are ways to counter both cost-push inflation and demand-pull inflation, which is through the implementation of different policies.

To counter cost-push inflation, supply-side policies need to be enacted with the goal of increasing aggregate supply. To increase aggregate supply, taxes can be decreased and central banks can implement contractionary monetary policies, achieved by increasing interest rates.

Countering demand-pull inflation would be achieved by the government and central bank implementing contractionary monetary and fiscal policies. This would include increasing the interest rate; the same as countering cost-push inflation because it results in a decrease in demand, decreasing government spending, and increasing taxes, all measures that would reduce demand.

Article Sources
Investopedia requires writers to use primary sources to support their work. These include white papers, government data, original reporting, and interviews with industry experts. We also reference original research from other reputable publishers where appropriate. You can learn more about the standards we follow in producing accurate, unbiased content in our editorial policy.
  1. OpenStax. “Principles of Economics: 11.3 Regulating Natural Monopolies,” Rice University, 2016.

  2. National Geographic. “Scarcity.”

  3. International Monetary Fund. “The Impact of Higher Oil Prices on the Global Economy,” Pages 4-5.

  4. Patrick J. Welch and Gerry F. Welch. “Economics: Theory and Practice,” Pages 117, 146. John Wiley & Sons, 2009.

  5. International Monetary Fund. “What Is Keynesian Economics?

  6. International Monetary Fund. “The Effects of Exchange Rate Fluctuations on Output and Prices: Evidence from Developing Countries,” Page 16-17.

  7. United States Congress Joint Economic Committee. “The Economics of Inflation and the Risks of Ballooning Government Spending.”

  8. International Monetary Fund. “Monetary Policy: Stabilizing Prices and Output.”

Open a New Bank Account
×
The offers that appear in this table are from partnerships from which Investopedia receives compensation. This compensation may impact how and where listings appear. Investopedia does not include all offers available in the marketplace.
Sponsor
Name
Description