At its most basic level, inflation is a general increase in prices across the economy and is well-known to all of us. After all, who among us has not reminisced about the cheap rents of the past or how little lunch used to cost?
And who has not noticed prices on everything from milk to movie tickets creeping upward? In this article, we explore the major types of inflation and touch upon the competing explanations offered by different economic schools.
We can define inflation with relative ease, but the question of what causes inflation is significantly more complex. Although numerous theories exist, arguably the two most influential schools of thought on inflation are those of Keynesian and monetarist economics.
Key Takeaways
- Inflation is the rate at which the overall level of prices for various goods and services in an economy rises over a period of time.
- As a result, money loses value because it no longer buys as much as it did in previous times; the purchasing power of a country's currency declines.
- Central banks look to maintain mild inflation of as much as 3% to help spur economic growth, but inflation considerably beyond that level could lead to brutal situations such as hyperinflation or stagflation.
- Hyperinflation is a period of fast-rising inflation; stagflation is a period of spiking inflation plus slow economic growth and high unemployment.
- Deflation is when prices drop significantly, due to too large a money supply or a slump in consumer spending; lower costs mean companies earn less and may institute layoffs.
Types of Inflation
Stagflation
Stagflation (a time of economic stagnation combined with inflation) can wreak havoc. This type of inflation is a witch’s brew of economic adversity, combining poor economic growth, high unemployment, and severe inflation all in one.
Although recorded instances of stagflation are rare, the phenomenon occurred as recently as the 1970s, when it gripped the United States and the United Kingdom—much to the dismay of both nations’ central banks.
Stagflation poses a particularly daunting challenge to central banks because it increases the risks associated with fiscal and monetary policy responses. Whereas central banks can usually raise interest rates to combat high inflation, doing so in a period of stagflation could risk further increasing unemployment.
Conversely, central banks are limited in their ability to decrease interest rates in times of stagflation because doing so could cause inflation to rise even further. As such, stagflation acts as a kind of check-mate against central banks, leaving them with no moves left to make. Stagflation is arguably the most difficult type of inflation to manage.
Hyperinflation
Although as consumers we may hate rising prices, many economists believe a moderate degree of inflation is healthy for a nation’s economy. Typically, central banks aim to maintain inflation around 2% to 3%. Increases in inflation significantly beyond this range can lead to fears of possible hyperinflation, a devastating scenario in which inflation rises rapidly out of control.
There have been several notable instances of hyperinflation throughout history. The most famous example is Germany during the early 1920s when inflation reached 30,000% per month. Zimbabwe offers an even more extreme example. According to research by Steve H. Hanke and Alex K. F. Kwok, monthly price increases in Zimbabwe reached an estimated 79,600,000,000% in November 2008.
Negative Inflation
Also known as deflation, negative inflation occurs when prices drop for various reasons. Having a smaller money supply increases the value of money, which in turn decreases prices. A reduction in demand either because there is too large of a supply or a reduction in consumer spending can also cause negative inflation.
Deflation may seem like a good thing because it reduces the prices of goods and services, thus making them more affordable, but it can negatively affect the economy in the long run. When businesses make less money on their products, they are forced to cut costs, which often means laying off or terminating employees, thereby increasing unemployment.
Keynesian economists argue inflation results from economic pressures such as the increased cost of production and look to government intervention as a solution; monetarist economists believe inflation stems from the expansion of the money supply and that central banks should maintain stable growth for the money supply in line with GDP.
Theories Explaining Inflation
Keynesian Economics
The Keynesian school believes inflation results from economic pressures such as rising costs of production or increases in aggregate demand.
Specifically, it distinguishes between two broad types of inflation: cost-push inflation and demand-pull inflation.
- Cost-push inflation results from general increases in the costs of the factors of production. These factors—which include capital, land, labor, and entrepreneurship—are the necessary inputs required to produce goods and services. When the cost of these factors rises, producers wishing to retain their profit margins must increase the price of their goods and services. When these production costs rise on an economy-wide level, it can lead to increased consumer prices throughout the whole economy, as producers pass on their increased costs to consumers. Consumer prices, in effect, are thus pushed up by production costs.
- Demand-pull inflation results from an excess of aggregate demand relative to aggregate supply. For example, consider a popular product where demand for the product outstrips supply. The price of the product would increase. The theory of demand-pull inflation is if aggregate demand exceeds aggregate supply, prices will increase economy-wide.
Monetarism
Monetarists have historically explained inflation as a consequence of an expanding money supply. The monetarist view is perfectly encapsulated by Friedman’s remark that “inflation is always and everywhere a monetary phenomenon.” According to this view, the principal factor underlying inflation has little to do with things like labor, materials costs, or consumer demand. Instead, it is all about the supply of money.
At the heart of this perspective is the quantity theory of money, which posits the relationship between the money supply and inflation is governed by the relationship
M∗V=P∗Twhere:M=The money supplyV=The velocity of moneyP=The average price levelT=The volume of transactions
Implicit in this equation is the belief that if the velocity of money and the volume of transactions are constant, an increase (or decrease) in the supply of money will cause a corresponding increase (or decrease) in the average price level.
Given that the velocity of money and the volume of transactions are in reality never constant, it follows that this relationship is not as straightforward as it may initially seem. Nevertheless, this equation serves as an effective model of the monetarists’ belief that the expansion of the money supply is the principal cause of inflation.
What Are the Different Causes of Inflation?
The main causes of inflation are classified as demand-pull inflation, cost-push inflation, and built-in inflation. Demand-pull inflation is when the demand for goods and services exceeds production capacity; cost-push inflation is when an increase in production costs increases prices; built-in inflation is when prices rise and wages rise too in order to maintain purchasing parity.
Who Benefits From Inflation?
When prices rise, borrowers generally benefit from inflation because they are paying back debts with money that has depreciated since prices increased. For example, if they have a fixed monthly payment of $1,000 and prices go up, that $1,000 is worth less than what it was before. Borrowers can also benefit from inflation as the increase in prices may result in people needing to borrow money more.
What Are the Worst Investments During Inflation?
During periods of inflation, some of the worst sectors to invest in are retail, durable goods, and technology. This is because when inflation happens, people tend to spend less due to the higher prices, and these sectors are often the ones where people begin to cut back on spending.
The Bottom Line
Inflation comes in many forms, from historically extreme cases of hyperinflation and stagflation to the five-cent and 10-cent increases we hardly notice. Economists from the Keynesian and monetarist schools disagree on the root causes of inflation, underscoring the fact that inflation is a far more complex phenomenon than one might initially assume.